Scandals about the award of public money to charities by way
of grants or contracts and companies through contracts are hardly new. Ancient
Rome was rocked by scandals about the contractors to the state. But a recent
case raises some major and fresh issues about how these arrangements should be
governed. The press has devoted acres of print to the collapse in 2015 of the
children's charity, Kids Company, led by the charismatic figure of Ms Camila
Batmanghelidjh, which had reportedly been awarded central government grants
over a period of more than a decade, despite government officials' concerns and
sometimes as a result of ministerial insistence. Several inquiries have been
instituted. We are still waiting for the result of one by the Charity
Commission into the way in which the charity was run and regulated, of one by
the Official Receiver into the manner in which the charity finally went bust,
and for the result of police investigations into abuse of children by some
people allegedly connected with the charity. But now finally we have a
fascinating, largely factual report carefully written without recommendations,
by the National Audit Office (NAO), which is the body responsible for checking
the propriety and value for money of government spending.
The NAO wasn't asked or expected to find new evidence about whether Kids
Company was effective or even cost-effective in the work it did with vulnerable
children. Rather, its task was to look at what government departments did with
the information they possessed about Kids Company, in making decisions about
whether or not to award new grants and contracts.
The bare
bones of the story have been reported widely. The NAO finds that government too
often relied on Kids Company's self-assessment reports; too often officials'
concerns about the quality of the charity's management and its financial
viability were set aside by ministers from both Labour and Coalition
governments who wanted to find a way to fund the organisation; and too often
government ministers and officials seem to have made decisions based on
imperatives to keep the organisation going rather than on the basis of
strategic procurement.
Cynics will
no doubt shrug and comment that at least these aspects of the tale could have
been told about government relationships with a great many defence contractors
over many decades, where the sums involved have been greater by orders of magnitude.
Yet,
carefully factual as it is, the NAO report highlights three questions which
deserve wider debate.
First, the
NAO note that each time Kids Company's central grant was about to expire, the
charity's leaders would lobby ministers and try to secure publicity in the mass
media for their campaign for renewal. Of course, charities have lobbied
government as much for their own grant aid as they have about wider policy
issues affecting their clientele, for as long as governments have been making grants
to them. In itself, this is hardly novel. Yet the emphasis that the NAO gives
to the issue suggests that there may be a shift in attitudes to the propriety
of this sort of lobbying. After all, if for-profit companies which are engaged
in competitive tendering lobbied for extensions and renewal contracts in the
same way that charities lobby for grant renewal, it is often regarded as
improper. Indeed, sometimes terms and conditions for tendering specifically
state that bodies which lobby for their bid will be excluded. The NAO report
raises the three related questions, “is lobbying for a grants still regarded as
more acceptable than lobbying for a contract?” and “is lobbying by a non-profit
charity on its own financial behalf still regarded as more acceptable than a
company doing so?” and “is an organisation lobbying for its own grant still
regarded as more acceptable in social welfare fields where clients are
disadvantaged than it is in government procurement of, for example, submarines
or cataracts operations or computer systems?”.
After all,
lobbying generally has been subject to increasing regulation around the world,
with new requirements for transparency, and much of the concern has been about
for-profit companies. Recent British legislation restricts even charities from
doing lobbying on wider policy issues in the periods immediately before
elections, if the political parties have positions on those topics.
The NAO
report makes no recommendations for further regulation but the question will
immediately occur to many readers, whether it might be desirable. It would not
be easy to design. Policing the boundary between lobbying for a policy change
and lobbying for one's own funding will not always be straightforward. It would
not be difficult to see how a rule against a charity lobbying for its own
funding might be abused by governments seeking to prevent lobbying on a wider
policy issue.
Moreover, it
would raise some tricky issues of fairness between charities and companies. For
when faced with closure, companies making steel, warships and even train
carriages have lobbied for government contracts to help them survive. Is this
different in principle from a charity lobbying for a government contract? Some
might say so. Some people would say that where a company is the largest single
employer in an area, lobbying for a state contract is really lobbying for
economic development for an area. Charities are hardly ever economically
critical to whole city or regional economies. But big charities which are dominant
in service provision in their field would no doubt say that lobbying for their
grants is tantamount to lobbying for their clientele. Critics, on the other
hand, would reply that this is precisely the problem – namely, that some
geographical communities are too dependent on company that have local
monopolies on employment and economic activity and that the more scattered
disadvantaged clienteles served by charities are too often dependent on
monopoly charities. But this, critics will say, is not an argument for the
state to prop up incumbents in either sector. In European competition law,
there is no difference between a government contract, grant or subsidy: all are
“state aids” and suspect, unless they are open to competition under open
government procurement rules, or subject to one of a limited number of
exemptions. Voluntary may lay claim to the grand rhetoric of “civil society”,
but the NAO report about Kids Company, in effect, asks us to consider afresh
whether we still think that when government awards grants and contracts to
charities, not least when they might be in difficulties, those charities should
be able to lobby for their own funding.
The second
issue raised by the NAO report is that government repeatedly found ways to
award to award contracts to Kids Company without a competitive process, using
special Charities Act 2006 powers. As the NAO puts it (para 4.18), ministers
can use these powers “for example as in this case to secure the continued
viability of a charity”. In the education department, a special Public Interest
Case was prepared to justify this, which, the NAO report says, did not present
a value-for-money assessment.
Government
contracts are sometimes awarded to companies without competitive processes too.
There are some special exemptions from competition permitted in procurement
rules. For example, innovative services which can't be defined in advance can
be bought under negotiated tender, and where patent or copyright provides for a
single supplier, competitive tendering can be dispensed with, and very small
contracts are not subject to the rules. But there is no general exemption from
competition in European procurement rules either for charities or for social
welfare activity or for aid by way of grants.
Many
charities, including Kids Company, would want to argue that they too offer
unique and innovative approaches, and some might even claim that the outcomes
cannot be specified in advance, although for continuing human services such as
supporting at-risk children the argument for unspecifiable outcomes is harder
to make that it might be for a contract for a one-off project with a brand new
technology.
Nowhere does
the NAO suggest anything so drastic as the repeal of the Charities Act powers
for ministers to award grants to charities on a non-competitive basis. But the
simple recounting of the facts implicitly raises the question of whether
attitudes are changing. Perhaps we are moving into an age in which the
non-profit sector, government grant aid and social welfare activity is now
regarded as a matter of public sector procurement just like government buying
civil servants laptops or the navy's submarines or high street dental services
for NHS dental care. For the issue is not just a matter of the scope for
ministerial patronage which ad hoc grant aid powers allow. It is also a
question of whether the rhetoric of “civil society” can still be used to
justify special exemption from open competition for awards from public funds,
and whether the viability of any private organisation, whether for-profit or
non-profit, should still be regarded as an acceptable objective for government
decision-making about the award of funds.
Third, the
NAO point out that throughout the history of Kids Company, officials were
anxious about the excessive reliance of the charity upon both central and local
government grants and contracts. Again, most defence contractors are in the
same position. There are big generalist companies which provide public services
under contract to public authorities and could be said to have been rather
dependent on government at various points in their recent history (although
some have diversified their revenue sources recently), including G4S, Serco,
Amey and Capita. Some specialist consulting firms depend on the NHS or on the
Department of Transport for their work. So if there is a special problem about
charities such as Kids Company, what is it? In some sections, the NAO report
suggests that officials were more anxious about the charity's dependence on
funds from central government and on grants than they were about either its
dependence on the wider public sector generally or on contracts; in other
passages, the concern is simply about excessive reliance on “government
funding”. At any rate, it seems from the report that this is a quite distinct
concern from those about, for example, the charity's lack of adequate reserves
or its too frequent financial emergencies.
A major
dilemma for government, in any procurement, is whether ministers and officials
should worry more about a supplier that doesn't need them or about one that
does. A supplier that doesn't depend on government for a huge proportion of its
income may not be amenable to change its practices so suit a public sector
client and may be able to resist the kinds of control that ministers and
officials might want or might even feel able to walk away from a contract when
the going gets tough and when this might be most inconvenient for government.
There are even companies which resist governments' invitations to them to
tender, precisely lest they become too dependent on the state, yet departments
might well prefer to buy from those companies than from those who will sell to
them. When big IT companies have walked away from government projects, they
have left departments with major problems and embarrassment. On the other hand,
a supplier that does depend on government for its revenues might be able to
hold its public sector client to ransom if its profile is high enough or if it
can make a case that government would be embarrassed should it fail (a fear
which, the NAO suggests, perhaps Kids Company was able to rely on for too
long).
The NAO
makes no suggestions of any new general rules about suppliers or even about
charities' dependence on government. But the repetition of the point about
officials' concerns being documented yet not leading to discontinuation of
awards until the final collapse in 2015 suggests that a fresh debate may be
opening up about this. If we no longer regard charities as being any different
from companies when public funds are being considered, then should we think of
some charities in the way that defence ministries have for so long regarded
their key suppliers of fighter jets and submarines, as both too important to be
allowed to fail and too important to be allowed NOT to be dependent on the
state? Or should the argument now run in precisely the opposite direction?
Should we now conclude that any organisation's excessive financial dependence
on the state, whether it is a charity or a firm, should be regarded as a risk
for government and should trigger an expectation that funding will actually be
reduced, unless some very special justification is given such as national
security, which few charities but some defence contractors might be able to show?
The sorry
tale of government's relationship with Kids Company may, in hard cash terms, be
a small one by comparison with huge scandals in contracting such as the US
government's contracts for reconstruction in Afghanistan, where the sums
involved were truly eye-watering and where the abuses were horrific. Yet the manner in which the NAO has written its report on the case suggests that
it may yet lead to debates that Britain has not conducted in very fundamental
terms for a generation, about whether the freedom of advocacy which charities
surely right have about policy issues affecting their clienteles can still
extend to lobbying for their own grants,
about just how different government's grants and contracts for charities
really are from its general procurement, and about whether a key criterion for
whether government should award any contract or grant to any organisation
should be whether that would take the proportion of its revenues from the state
over a certain threshold unless there is some special justification such as
national security.
To put the
point bluntly, in a way that the NAO never would or could, the issues raised in
this report ask Britain to debate whether the voluntary sector's rhetoric about
“civil society” and the facts charities do not pay dividends to shareholders
and may serve disadvantaged clients still afford a justification for special
treatment in law and practice of public procurement. That is not only a public
management question. It is also a question about what kind of country Britain
will regard itself as.
No comments:
Post a Comment