Source |
Now that the
Scottish voters have rejected independence by a modest majority, debates begin
in earnest and with urgency about what can happen next. This third post in the
series considers the implications of the discussion about decentralisation
within England, following the prime minister's remarks in his speech in
response to the referendum result.
Mr Cameron said
on the morning of 19th September “It is also important we have wider
civic engagement about to improve governance in our United Kingdom, including
how to empower our great cities. And we will say more about this in the coming
days.”
Debate about
this has been intense over several years. A series of commissions has published
reports, including the City Growth Commission chaired by investor Jim O'Neill
(its final report is due next month). But we cannot yet know which approach the
government will propose. So here I confine myself to specific issues which have
got lost in the mist of general encomium for the principle of greater
decentralisation, but which will present major challenges of public management.
The
corollary: more local self-reliance
If new and
additional powers to spend public money are given to sub-national bodies at
their discretion without having to secure the approval of the Treasury, then
they will almost certainly be accompanied by tax arrangements which mean
raising more funds at sub-national level and each city or region or locality
having to rely more on what it can raise locally and less on central grants.
This will likely be true for two reasons. The first is political. Ministers who
agree to give away powers will want to be sure that they are also handing over
the political exposure for blame when things go wrong and, conversely, that
they are acquiring the right to lead the blaming. The second is financial, and
will be important to the Treasury. If the Treasury is to be persuaded or
required by ministers to hand over control of parts of public expenditure, it
will insist that with those powers go disciplines. And the key discipline will
be some kind of budgeting rule that restricts exposure to losses on the central
exchequer. The “prudential” limit on borrowing by sub-national authorities will
come under strain, as the Treasury seeks to find ways to reduce total public
sector debt in a decentralised England.
If the unit to
which powers are devolved is the local council in its current form or at least
the ones for the big cities, then the first and biggest consequence of new
powers will be higher council tax bills and business rates so that these
sources of revenue make up a bigger share of their spending as they exercise
their new powers. Explaining this to voters and to businesses will be hard
enough.
If this is not
matched by corresponding reductions in other national taxes, it will be even
harder.
The second
consequence will be the dwindling of the equalisation of resources among
councils which has long been in place, to limit the extent to which poor areas
unable to raise much more revenue locally would be left without compensation
from central grants. There are perfectly respectable long term arguments for
this, which claim that even if the effect is greater inequality, making fiscal
self-reliance the corollary of new powers for localities will unleash
innovation and creativity, will give councils incentives to try to transform
their areas to attract people and businesses able to create jobs which will
enable them eventually to raise more revenue, and that the responsibility of a
greater degree of fiscal self-reliance will cultivate greater capacity and
skill and political responsibility among elected councillors and among local
government managers.
But there is no
avoiding the consequence of greater inequality. Poor and economically declining
areas such as the impoverished seaside towns and inland post-industrial areas
which have weak transport links will be pessimistic that they can sustain their
services as equalisation is reduced and may be gloomy that any kind of local bootstrapping
economic development programme will transform their prospects in time before
fiscal self-reliance leads to even further capital flight than they have
already experienced.
The political
debate of the next decade will be about whether the observable, measurable
improvements in innovations, incentives and local economic development achieved
in absolute terms are worth the greater relative inequality. One can argue that
if we want a more mature democratic debate about local and other tiers of sub-national
government, that is precisely the right question about which we should be
disagreeing more explicitly. And certainly increasing the proportion of public
expenditure for which local councils are responsible for spending and
collecting revenues to support from the current position, which is the lowest
in western Europe and one of the lowest in the OECD will have that effect. But
if England is to embark on this, following Mr Cameron's speech, then we ought
to go into it with the firm expectation that the debate could become
politically polarised.
Handing over
national taxes or just allowing changes to the rates of local taxes?
On the day that
Scots were voting to remain in the union, Labour MP Margaret Hodge published an
article in the London Evening Standard arguing that London should not only keep more of the tax revenues raised in the
city, so that in effect they would not be redistributed to poorer areas of
England, but that as well as greater freedoms to vary rates of council tax and
business rates the revenues from a series of national taxes should be
transferred to London. Part of her argument was that the money would enable
London to reduce inequality within the city. But the obverse of that coin is
that the reduced funds available for redistribution away from wealthy London to
the rest of the country could mean greater inequality in spending on public
services when measured nationally.
Mrs Hodge's
argument is the opening salvo in a long battle about just which kinds of tax
powers might be transferred from the Treasury. Her was that as well as powers
to increase council tax and business rates, the national taxes of stamp duty
and capital gains tax on property should be transferred. The City Growth
Commission's report on city finance talks of new property taxes for cities. For a long time there have been
proposals made that cities could take on benefits budgets and use them in
different ways, by redesigning schemes, and that these might be supported by
national taxes but ones where the locally raised element would not be pooled
but hypothecated and handed over by the Revenue and Customs to city
authorities.
Clearly, the
more that yields from national taxes or new taxes are ring fenced for
localities, the steeper the inequality effect between areas, at least in the
short run before any resulting dynamism does its hoped-for work.
The immediate
effect of Mr Cameron's announcement that he will bring forward plans will be to
pit central departments and sub-national bodies against each other in deep
rivalry in the process of policymaking.
What will the
unit be?
There will now
be a fierce debate about just what it should be, that is given decentralised
powers and fiscal responsibilities. Local government will press its case that
all councils should benefit. The mood of the prevailing argument in recent
months has tended to privilege major cities only. Increasingly, though,
international debates about economic development have concentrated on the city
region. This is variously defined. Some commentators use it to mean the city and
its immediate environs – for example, the administrative area of greater
London. For others, it means the travel-to-work area. But for London, much of
the workforce for which arrives daily by train from as far afield as Sheffield
and Manchester, that is a huge area. There are advocates of a single grand city
region stretching from Liverpool in the west to Leeds in the east, for which
they hope to develop a common transport infrastructure and common economic
development programme. At the moment, City Deals and Local Enterprise
Partnerships (LEPs) often span several authorities. The Labour government tried
to offer decentralisation to whole regions, but failed to secure acceptance
even in the north east, where a referendum rejected a plan for a regional assembly
with tax raising powers to match the powers of that government's regional
development programme and its agencies.
But geographical
boundaries are not the only dimension of the “what unit?” question. Because
LEPs don't yet raise many taxes in their own names (some are involved in
collecting business rates on their council members behalf and with the consent
of their business members), it has not been very important that citizens may
not recognise them or regard them as having political credibility. When a major
programme of decentralisation within England begins, there will have to be some
way of securing public recognition and acceptance of and perhaps even
identification with whatever units are given powers and responsibilities.
Although there
are no good technical reasons for thinking that we need a single tier of
agencies to give devolved powers and taxing authority, and indeed very good
economic and service design reasons why personal social services, waste
collection, transport and economic development should be pursued by very
differently sized units, the politics of being taxed tend not to work like
that. Citizens who want representation if they are to accept greater taxation
at sub-national level will want representation at the smallest number of tiers.
They will do so, as much for reasons of what they can identify with as members
of named communities as for reasons of reducing the numbers of tiers of
politicians to the minimum necessary.
The debate on
which England is about to embark, following Mr Cameron's announcement, will pit
the tiers of sub-national governance against each other in ferocious
competition for powers and for credibility.
Can
decentralisation be achieved while cutting spending?
The coalition
government's projections for public spending during the 2015-2020 parliament
are eye-watering. If NHS care, secondary schooling and pensions continue to be
protected even to the level they have been, then the reductions assumed by the
numbers published will be very painful indeed. Even Labour accepts that
austerity of some kind must continue for the duration of the next parliament if
fiscal credibility is to be achieved.
This puts a huge
strain on any plan which Mr Cameron announces for decentralisation. If the
Treasury insists that the whole programme must be kept within the bounds of the
falling totals for public expenditure, then the subnational governing bodies
will be given a larger share of a shrinking pie. Securing their commitment to
that will be difficult but not so difficult as explaining to citizens and
businesses why their council tax and business rates will rise, even if other
taxes fall, at a time when services will still have to be cut. Limiting the
increase in inequality resulting from greater fiscal self-reliance when
spending is also falling for at least five years in nominal as well as real
terms will be very difficult.
In sum, Mr
Cameron has started a process which will become imbrangled quickly in
technicalities, which will be hard to explain and justify to the public when
visible local tax rates rise, which will raise serious difficulties about the
extent of relative inequality across England even if there is continued
improvement in the absolute level of GDP and in the national average quality of
some public services, and which will hugely strain the relationship between
overall fiscal discipline and sub-national autonomy. If it comes to be accepted
that the settlement with Scotland cannot be achieved without some kind of
decentralisation in England, then these four difficulties will dominate the
politics of the public services in England for years to come.
No comments:
Post a Comment